WP/14/79 European Productivity, Innovation and Competitiveness: The Case of Italy Andrew Tiffin  2013 International monetary fund WP/14/79 IMF Working Paper Strategy, Policy, and Review Department European Productivity, Innovation and Competitiveness: The Case of Italy Prepared by Andrew Tiffin Authorized for distribution by Vikram Haksar and Ken Kang May 2014 Abstract In Italy, price-based competitiveness measures are not always an accurate predictor of trade outcomes. This paper offers a more comprehensive assessment of Italian competitiveness, focusing on the role of innovation and the evolution of Italyâ s export market share. Overall, Italy maintains a high-quality export mix, and the adaptability of small-scale specialized firms is still a source of strength. But, small firm size is becoming less of an asset, and even the most innovative sectors are weighed down by the structural barriers that have depressed productivity more broadly. Italyâ s future competitiveness will depend on full implementation of a comprehensive structural-reform agenda JEL Classification Numbers: F14; F41; O30; O31 Keywords: Italy, competitiveness, exports, shift share analysis, CMSA Authorâ s E-mail Address: atiffin@imf. org This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author (s) and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy. Working papers describe research in progress by the author (s) and are published to elicit comments and to further debate 2 Contents Page I. Introduction...3â II. The Italian Competitiveness Puzzle...3â A a Collapse in Competitiveness without a Collapse in Exports...3â B. Productivity, Innovation, and Exports...4â III. Price Competitiveness...8â A. Unit Labor Costs vs. Price-Based Measures...8â B. Supply-Chain Based Indicators...9â IV. Non-Price Competitiveness...10â A. Quality Indicators...10â V. Market-Share Dynamics...11â A. Shift-Share Analysis...11â B. Results: Sources of Innovation and Market Share...12â VI. Conclusion...14â Table 1. Changes in World Market Share and Shift-Share Decomposition...16â Figure 1. Exports Shares, by Industry Group...7â Appendix A. Shift-Share Analysis and Competitiveness...19â References...21â 3 I. INTRODUCTION Italyâ s economic performance over the past two decades has been disappointing. In contrast to the 1970s and 1980s, when it stood out as the best growth performer among its major European partners, Italy has suffered a steady and prolonged decline in growth since the 1990s. And in the context of the recent financial crisis, the legacy of this slump has arguably made Italyâ s recession deeper and more persistent than in many of its peers. This is not simply an issue for Italy alone. The sustainability of Italyâ s public debt (already over 120 percent of GDP) is sensitive to the evolution of future output growthâ making Italyâ s growth prospects a matter of concern for the entire Eurozone and beyond (Eichengreen 2011 Much of the discussion of Italyâ s performance has centered on declining productivity and an associated deterioration in competitiveness. For example, an examination of Unit Labor Costs (ULC) suggests that rising wages in Italy, although relatively modest by regional standards, have outpaced nonetheless productivity growth by a substantial margin; placing Italy at a growing disadvantage compared to its European peers. 1 But, measuring competitiveness is far from straight forwardâ there is no agreed definition, or well-defined set of indicators. Indeed, âoecompetitivenessâ is multifaceted a somewhat concept which continues to evolve in line with a rapidly changing global economy This paper will offer a comprehensive assessment of Italyâ s external competitiveness focusing in particular on Italian export performanceâ an ex post measure that captures the extent to which countries gain or lose market share in external markets. Relative prices or costs may be an important driver of this performance. But non-price factors, such as innovation, specialization, and quality will also play a role. The opening sections of the paper will present some of the standard price -and cost-based indicators, outlining how they might perhaps be augmented in the context of an increasingly integrated global economy. The following sections will then focus on the evolution of Italyâ s export share; focusing in particular on the role of innovation in shaping the economyâ s continued trading success. The concluding section will outline some implications for the Italian authoritiesâ structural reform agenda II. THE ITALIAN COMPETITIVENESS PUZZLE A a Collapse in Competitiveness without a Collapse in Exports Over the past two decades, discussion of the Italian economy has centered increasingly on the key themes of weak growth and competitiveness. In this regard, a sustained drop in total factor productivity (TFP) growth, and the resulting increase in unit labor costs relative to 1 See the Staff Report for the 2012 Article IV Consultations for Italy (IMF Country Report 12/167 4 Top 10 Manufacturers by Value Added Current USD 2000 2010 Source: UN Stats Italyâ s main EU competitors have raised repeated concerns about the competitiveness of Italyâ s exporters. A typical diagnosis points to notes an underlying reform gap in Italy; which has produced a stagnant economy and a labor market in which average earnings are largely decoupled from productivity and demand conditions. With Italian trading partners introducing productivity-enhancing reforms, and with the historical escape route of competitive devaluation unavailable, this has resulted supposedly in a sizable competitiveness gap, which has weighed down on investment, confidence and growth Manasse, 2013 Against this backdrop, however, Italian exports have held up relatively well (in value terms. In an era dominated by the dramatic expansion of emerging -market exporters, Italyâ s tradable sector continues to rank among the worldâ s leadersâ in contrast to many other European countries. And Italyâ s share of world exports has moved generally in parallel with its European peers. Most recently, the buoyancy of exports in the face of depressed global demand has underscored the continued adaptability and resilience of Italian trading firms. Indeed, according to the WTO/UNCTAD s Trade Performance Index, Italy remains the worldâ s top-ranked exporter in textiles clothing and leather goods; and is ranked second in the world (behind Germany) for non-electronic machinery and manufactures (basic and miscellaneous B. Productivity, Innovation, and Exports Part of the key to this puzzle may lie in the nature of Italyâ s productivity challenge. Although the underlying causes of Italyâ s poor productivity are still topics of active debate, part of the explanation most likely involves the changing nature of production, and the increased importance of innovation in securing sustained output growth (Aghion, 2011. As illustrated in the figure below, the Italian productivity experience is amplified perhaps an version of the average) European experience; in which a process of trend convergence with the world leader ended in the mid 1990s, coinciding roughly with the information and communications technology (ICT) revolution (Bank of Italy, 2009. This latter development has often been described as a game-changing eventâ analogous to the introduction of steam or electricityâ that has changed dramatically the nature of global production, as well as the requirements for firms and countries wishing to maintain their position at the global frontier (Crafts, 2012. In this regard, the ICT revolution has expanded potentially the scope for firms to distinguish between 5 i. Technological competitiveness, which is associated with the development of new products and requires substantial internal innovation (research development, and design; and ii. Cost competitiveness, which is associated instead with improved efficiency and lower labor costs (see Bogliacino & Pianta, 2010 For Italian firms facing increased cost-based competition from emerging-market exporters the former has perhaps become more and more important This paper will explore the extent to which the performance of Italian exporters reflects their relative ability to innovate and adapt to a changing global environment. Although the economy as a whole may have faced difficulty integrating and exploiting new technologies to boost performanceâ reflecting perhaps a broad range of structural and administrative impedimentsâ it may be that Italian exporters have had better success. To this end, the chapter will separate Italyâ s exporting industries by their sources of innovation: extending the Pavitt (1984) Industrial Taxonomy, and separating each export industry into one of five separate groups: 2 ï Science-based industries, such as pharmaceuticals, high-end electronics, and aviation which are dominated by large firms, and where innovation is typically internal to the firm and based on advances in science ï Specialized Supplier industries; which are often dominated by smaller firms that design, develop and produce equipment tailored specifically to a particular production process or need ï Traditional industries, such as textiles, furniture, food, and basic manufactures; where internal innovation is less relevant, and new technology comes from external suppliers of equipment and material 2see Kubielas (2007) for a Pavitt-based classification of each industry by ISIC Rev. 3 20 30 40 50 60 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 GDP per Hour (in 2012 USD ICT Revolutionproductivity Gap Narowing Productivity Gap Widening Source: The Conference Board, Total Economy Database 6 0 %20 %40 %60 %80 %100 %1995 2007 2011 Export Shares, by Industry Group Science-Based Specialized-Supplier Traditional Scale-Based (Tech Scale-Based (Resource Source: COMTRADE, IMF staff calculations ï Scale-Intensive industries; where innovations are derived mainly from the exploitation of economies of scale. These can be broken further down into ï Technology-based scale-intensive industries, such as motor vehicles and other transport equipment ï Resource-based scale-intensive industries, such as industrial chemicals refined petroleum products, basic metals, and processed foodstuffs Italyâ s export mix has a substantial weight of traditional products, but also has a large proportion stemming from specialized -suppliers. Indeed, although a key development over the past 15 years has been the shrinking importance of the traditional sector, and the growing importance of scale-intensive resource -based industries, a more singular feature of Italyâ s export mix is the large and stable share originating from specialized suppliers. In comparison to other countries, the share owing to these suppliers is more akin to that seen in Germany or the United states (Figure 1 It is specialized the-supplier sector that has often been viewed as a key source of Italyâ s export prowess. Firms in this sector tend to be small and medium in size, with a marked capacity for incremental innovation and a diversified range of high-quality, high-margin products with few substitutes (such as machine tools, precision instruments, and specialized machinery for industry and agriculture. Often organized within a flexible network of small firms or industrial districts, it is the inventiveness and agility of this sector that has been highlighted in the past as one of the main factors allowing Italy to maintain its relative world position. 3 This paper will explore the extent to which this sector has continued to remain competitive despite apparently adverse developments across Italyâ s price-based competitiveness indicators 3see Porter (1990) and Ginsborg (2003 7 Figure 1. Exports Shares, by Industry Group Sources: COMTRADE, Fund staff calculations Deviation from EU average, percentage points -10 -5 0 5 10 Science-Based Specialized Supplier Traditional Scale-Based (tech Scale-Based (resource -10 -5 0 5 10 -10 -5 0 5 10 -10 -5 0 5 10 -10 -5 0 5 10 -10 -5 0 5 10 8 III. PRICE COMPETITIVENESS A. Unit Labor Costs vs. Price-Based Measures Italyâ s standard price-competitiveness indicators present a mixed picture. Although the dispersion of different competitiveness indexes is a feature in many European countries, it is particularly evident in Italy, where ULC-based indicators routinely suggest a substantially larger loss in competitiveness compared to other CPI-or PPI-based indicators (Bayoumi and others, 2011. Using a total-economy ULC-based measure, Italyâ s competitiveness appears to have deteriorated by up to 5 percent since adoption of the euro, compared to an improvement in Germany of nearly 20 percent. Using a PPI-based measure, on the other hand, the gap between the two countries is considerably narrower, and Italy is not materially less competitive than it was in 1999 But labor-cost measures may present an incomplete picture, and should perhaps be complemented. Part of the discrepancy between the different types of measures may again reflect the changing nature of global production. In an era of globalization and international supply chains, the share of domestically employed labor in total production costs is decreasing, albeit to a different degree in different countriesâ indeed, wage shares in the manufacturing sector fell sharply in Germany between 1998 and 2007, but only marginally in Italy over the same period (Giordano & Zollino, 2013. Labor-cost-based indicators therefore, may reflect a subset of costs that are perhaps becoming less and less representative and so may not accurately represent Italyâ s overall price competitiveness. Similarly, drawing on the above distinction between technological competitiveness and cost competitiveness rising wages may reflect the creation of higher-level jobs in an increasingly innovative and technologically competitive economy. As a sign of deteriorating competitiveness, therefore such cost-based measures may tend to overstate the problem. Arguably, price-based indicators may provide a better guide 70 80 90 100 110 120 PPI-Based 70 80 90 100 110 120 ULC-Based Harmonized Competitiveness Indicators, 1999-2012 Index, end 1998=100 Source: Bank of Italy, ECB, IMF staff calculations 9 -15 -10 -5 0 5 Costs Prices Supply-Chain Based Real Effective Exchange rates Cumulative Appreciation, percent, 1999-2012 Source: Bayoumi, Saito & Turunen (2013 B. Supply-Chain Based Indicators IMF Staff have developed alternative measures that address the implications of global supply chains on the assessment of price competitiveness. Conventional measures are typically not well suited to instances when imports are used to produce exports, as they tend to assume that countries compete against one another to sell â productsâ that they produce entirely at home, using only domestic inputs. A possible alternative, the âoevalue-added Real Effective Exchange rate (VA-REER), â tackles this issue by adapting the usual REER framework to a world in which countries compete in the supply of value-added (or âoetasksâ) rather than goods Bems & Johnson, 2012. In this framework, to take the typical example, China is not competing with other countries in the supply of iphones, but rather in the supply of final -assembly services, which form only a small portion of the iphoneâ s final price. Accounting for a countryâ s supply-chain position, and improving on the (labor-focused) ULC indicator in the previous section, the VA-REER thus captures the overall cost competitiveness of the full range of a countryâ s factors of production. A similar approach addresses the same issue by instead modifying the standard price-based REER approach, to include an additional term that reflects the role of outsourcing in offsetting the impact of domestic factor-price inflation Bayoumi, Saito, & Turunen, 2013. This measure is focused therefore more on the actual price competitiveness of a countryâ s gross exports, rather than its factors of production For Italy, the differences between these alternative supply-chain measures are illustrative Considering the cumulative real appreciation since adoption of the euro, the (modified) cost -based VA-REER for Italy gives roughly the same assessment as a standard (unmodified CPI-based REER; which in turn provides a less pessimistic assessment than the standard unmodified) ULC measure. The modified price-based measure, on the other hand, suggests an even less-marked decline in competitiveness than the VA-REER. Overall, this suggests that rising factor costs in Italy have not translated into an equivalent increase in the relative price of Italian goods, owing in part to role of low-cost imports from low inflation countries Interestingly, Germany presents the opposite picture. The sharp increase in competitiveness implied by falling factor costs in Germany has not been matched fully by lower export prices owing to the fact that Germany imports a large and increasing proportion of its inputs from countries with relatively high inflation Looking at a wide range of indicators therefore, the competitiveness challenge in Italy may not be as immediately dire as suggested by a focus solely on cost-based measures 10 IV. NON-PRICE COMPETITIVENESS A. Quality Indicators The relative strength of Italian exporters may also reflect their ongoing efforts to fend off competition by upgrading the quality of their products. Past Fund Staff research has emphasized the important role of non-price factors in supporting Italyâ s export performance Lissovolik, 2008), and quality upgrades have featured prominently in this regard (Codogno 2009). ) Export quality cannot be observed directly, but the clearest evidence of this trend is in the persistent upward movement of export unit values, which are taken generally as a key proxy for quality. Indeed, averaging across all export sectors, unit values in Italy are around 1â times higher than the global mean. 4 Recent Fund staff research confirms Italyâ s continued success in maintaining the high quality of its export mix. Although unit values are useful, they are a somewhat noisy indicator of quality, as they also reflect a range of other factors, including cost differences. Henn Papageorgiou, & Spatafora (2013) calculate a more consistent, less noisy, set of quality indicators; based on unit values, but estimated within a sector-specific gravity-equation framework. The results suggest that Italy remains at the top of the global quality ladder across all its major exports, even those associated with more traditional industries The above non-price developments all highlight the difficulty of assessing a countryâ s competitiveness on the basis of a select few price-or cost-based measures. In a stable world economy, changes in competitiveness might indeed be captured by changes in relative prices. In an evolving global economy, however, a countryâ s competitiveness may also reflect the ability of its exporting firms to adapt successfully to a changing external environment; upgrading the quality and composition of their export mix 4wto/UNCTAD relative unit-value data is available at: http://www. intracen. org/country/italy /0 10 20 30 40 0 2 4 6 8 1 1 2 Q ua lit y I nd ex 1 =9 0t h pe rc en til e Pe rc en t o f E xp or ts Export Share (RHS) Italy Positionquality Ladder Fo od Be v & To ba cc o Cr ud e M at er ia ls M in er al s An im al & V eg O ils Ch em ica ls M an uf G oo ds M ac hi n & Tr an sp or t M isc M an uf ac tu re s O th er Italy: Export Quality by Sector, 2009 Source: Henn, Papageorgiou & Spatafora (2013 -10 -5 0 5 10 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 Export Unit Value percent change, y/y Source: ISTAT, IMF staff calculations 11 rapidly seeking out new destinations, building a global reputation, outsourcing low value -added activities, and identifying new high-margin niches. Micro data on Italian firms confirms that this indeed has been a large part of the Italian storyâ where the manufacturing sector has undergone a significant process of ongoing restructuring over the past 20 years with a significant impact on overall export performance (Leichter, Mocci, and Pozzuoli 2011 V. MARKET-SHARE DYNAMICS A. Shift-Share Analysis In light of the mixed picture presented above, perhaps a more telling indicator of Italian competitiveness is the ex post evolution of its global market share. But a simple investigation of markets shares raises the following issue: two countries with similarly competitive exporting firms may nonetheless display different performances over the short-to medium-term, if one has a more favorable mix of products (at the time), or if it exports to a particularly dynamic set of destinations. A more representative measure of a countryâ s underlying competitiveness, therefore, will strip out such product and geographical effects The following analysis employs a shift-share approach to arrive at an âoeadjustedâ measure of market-share growth. Also known as constant market-share analysis (CMSA), shift-share analysis (SSA) is an econometric approach that allows the decomposition of changes in a countryâ s market share over time. The key intuition is that a countryâ s export growth does not occur in a vacuum, but is shaped instead by: the growth of world trade itself; the countryâ s mix of trading partners; and the bundle of goods that it exports. Keeping all these factors constant, a countryâ s market share should also remain constantâ but if it decreases even after for controlling for its export/destination mix, then this adjusted market share serves as a key sign that the countryâ s exporters are underperforming. In the following analysis, market shares are measured in value terms, and so incorporate the non-price competitiveness factors outlined above The approach is outlined in detail in the appendix, and is fixed based on a-effects regression of detailed bilateral trade flows. Drawing on the methodology outlined by Cheptea (2005 and revised by Bricongne and others (2013), the methodology starts with the following equation 0 5 10 0 5 10 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Share of World Exports (percent Italy Germany France UK Japan China Source: DOTS, IMF staff calculations 12 à¢á à¢à¢à¢à¢à oe à¢à¢à¢à à¢à¢à¢à à¢à¢à¢à ࢿ¢à¢à¢à¢à ¢Where Î it, Î jt, and Î kt are exporter, importer, and product fixed effects that can vary across time. The dependent variable á Ü à oeà à à§is disaggregated export growth; based on a midpoint measure so as to take into account the possibility of entry and exit from a particular export line (i e.,, the extensive margin of trade. For any country, estimation of these fixed effects allows the decomposition of market-share growth into three separate components ï A sectoral component measuring growth due to the mix of products exported ï A geographical component capturing changes due to the distribution of trading partners ï An âoeadjustedâ market share, or performance component that reflects growth due to a countryâ s underlying price and non-price competitiveness The estimation draws from the bilateral dataset developed by Gaulier & Zingano (2010 which provides reconciled values of all international trade flows for about 5000 product headings from the 6-digit Harmonized System (HS) classification over the years 1995â 2011 See Appendix I for a more detailed treatment of the methodology and dataset B. Results: Sources of Innovation and Market Share For exports as a whole, like most other advanced-market countries, Italyâ s share of global exports has fallen with the introduction of emerging-market exporters into the global trading system. A detailed decomposition of growth rates for a number of countries is presented in Table 1, but for the precrisis period (1995â 2007), the figure below suggests that Italy has generally managed to orient its exports to markets with a rapidly expanding demand for imports, while its product mix has been biased towards products where growth has been less dynamic. 5 Taking these two effects into account, it appears that Italyâ s adjusted market share measure, although disappointing, is not as critical as it might appear at first. Indeed, its underlying competitiveness compares favorably to countries such as France or the United Kingdom, and is broadly comparable to that of Germany. Looking at export-share developments over the post crisis period (2007â 11), most European countries suffered from a sudden downturn in demand from their main (European) export partners. And again, Italy seems to have been held additionally back by a poor product mix, but the adjusted measure is nonetheless broadly in line with that of France or the United states, where price -competitiveness measures have typically been more favorable than those in Italy 5the sample length is chosen to take advantage of the full dataset, but it should be noted that this period includes a number of years prior to the introduction of the euro, when Italian exports were still benefitting from the lira devaluation of the early 1990s. This devaluation may have created additional room to absorb the loss of competitiveness recorded in subsequent years 13 Focusing on science-based industries, Italian exporters have generally been much more successful in targeting products with better prospects for growth. Indeed, Italy has mostly managed to maintain or even increase its market share in this sector. But this represents only a small fraction of Italian exports, and the adjusted market-share measure paints a less rosy picture; suggesting that exporters in this sector are still being held back by an underlying lack of competitiveness Turning to specialized suppliers, Italy again seems to have had some success in focusing on high-growth products, but the underlying competitiveness measure is nonetheless worrisome In context, the competitiveness of the sector is perhaps not an issue of critical concernâ as it still fares favorably compared to countries like France and the United kingdom, and historically is not too far removed from Germany. But looking forward, the fact that weak underlying competitiveness continues to erode Italyâ s global market share suggests that specialized-supplier exports may not be the source of strength that they once were. Partly Decomposition of Market Share Growth, All Exports percent annualized -6 -3 0 3 JPN UK USA FRA ITA GER PRT ESP 1995-2007 Product Mix Geography Adj. Mkt Share Mktshare -6 -3 0 3 UK USA JPN ITA FRA ESP GER PRT 2007-2011 -15 -10 -5 0 5 JPN ITA UK USA FRA GER ESP PRT 1995-2007 Product Mix Geography Adj. Mkt Share Mktshare -15 -10 -5 0 5 USA UK PRT JPN ITA GER ESP FRA 2007-2011 Decomposition of Market Share Growth, Science-Based Exporters percent annualized 14 this may be the cumulative result of the distortions, rigidities, and administrative impediments that have helped stifle growth in the broader Italian economy; and which are now weighing even on this once-dynamic sector. Alternatively, it may also reflect the changing nature of global production; where larger scale firms now tend to be more successful in generating worldwide brand recognition, securing access to finance, and integrating into global supply chains. And where small firm sizeâ which once helped ensure the agility and resilience of the Italian export sectorâ is now less of an asset. Indeed, from a policy viewpoint, if firm size and global reach are now more important, there is perhaps a growing need for structural reforms that can remove the barriers to firm growth and encourage inward FDI. These reforms would also help the science-based sector described above, which appears relatively successful, but so far is only a small part of Italyâ s export base VI. CONCLUSION In Italy, as in many countries, price competitiveness measures have not always served as an accurate guide to subsequent trade developments. These measures, such as relative unit labor costs, are simple to communicate and are linked often closely to the instruments available to policy makers. But globalization is reshaping the relationship between trade performance and price factors, with the latter providing less and less explanatory power for export growth (Di Mauro and others, 2008 This paper has offered a more comprehensive assessment of Italyâ s competitiveness. In light of the dispersion of Italyâ s price -and cost-based indicators, it is perhaps more instructive to look at the ex post evolution of Italyâ s export market share; focusing in particular on the non -price factorsâ such as quality, innovation, and flexibilityâ that have underpinned Italyâ s success in the past. The overall appraisal is that Italian competitiveness is indeed a matter of concern; although perhaps not as critical as some assessments have claimed. Indeed, Italyâ s underlying competitiveness (as captured by the evolution of its adjusted market share -8 -4 0 UK JPN USA FRA ITA GER ESP PRT 1995-2007 Product Mix Geography Adj. Mkt Share Mktshare -8 -4 0 FRA ITA USA ESP UK PRT JPN GER 2007-2011 Decomposition of Market Share Growth, Specialized Product Exporters percent annualized 15 compares favorably to many of its peers. Italy still maintains a high-quality export mix, and the adaptability of Italian firms is still a source of strength. But even the most innovative and flexible sectors are being weighed down by the structural impediments that have depressed Italian productivity more broadly. 6 Italyâ s future competitiveness will thus depend on the institutional and macroeconomic conditions that allow productive firms to innovate and expand, which in turn will require the successful implementation of the authoritiesâ full structural-and institutional-reform agenda 6 This analysis does not identify these specifically, but these include labor -and product-market rigidities, high network-industry costs (e g. electricity) and a relatively inefficient and overburdened judicial system. For more detail, a comprehensive treatment of Italyâ s main economy-wide bottlenecks is provided in the most recent Article IV Staff Reports for Italy; available at http://www. imf. org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2013/cr13298. pdf and http://www. imf. org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2012/cr12167. pdf 16 Table 1. Changes in World Market Share and Shift-share Decomposition Large Exporters, 1995â 2011 Market Adjusted Share Mkt Share Geography Product Mix All Export Industries China 1995-2007 8. 6 12.8-1. 8-2. 0 2007-2011 5. 1 6. 6 0. 0-1. 4 France 1995-2007-2. 1-3. 1 0. 4 0. 6 2007-2011-3. 4-2. 4-1. 5 0. 4 Germany 1995-2007-0. 1-1. 3 0. 6 0. 5 2007-2011-2. 0-0. 5-1. 3-0. 3 Italy 1995-2007-1. 5-1. 4 0. 4-0. 6 2007-2011-4. 1-2. 6-1. 2-0. 3 Japan 1995-2007-3. 8-4. 3-0. 2 0. 7 2007-2011-1. 5-2. 6 2. 1-0. 9 Portugal 1995-2007-1. 4-0. 3 0. 3-1. 4 2007-2011-0. 7 3. 3-3. 3-0. 6 Spain 1995-2007 0. 6 0. 6-0. 1 0. 1 2007-2011-2. 3-0. 6-1. 5-0. 2 United kingdom 1995-2007-2. 9-3. 7 0. 1 0. 8 2007-2011-5. 0-4. 0-1. 7 0. 7 USA 1995-2007-2. 6-3. 5 0. 3 0. 6 2007-2011-1. 7-3. 1 1. 1 0. 4 Science-Based Industries China 1995-2007 15.7 21.1-1. 1-3. 4 2007-2011 6. 3 11.5 0. 3-5. 0 France 1995-2007-0. 4-3. 1 0. 3 2. 4 2007-2011 2. 6 0. 4-0. 1 2. 3 Germany 1995-2007 2. 1 0. 0 0. 1 2. 0 2007-2011 0. 4-1. 3-1. 1 2. 8 Italy 1995-2007-1. 2-4. 7 0. 2 3. 4 2007-2011 1. 6-1. 7-0. 9 4. 3 Japan 1995-2007-12.1-9. 5 0. 3-3. 1 2007-2011-6. 3-4. 6-0. 1-1. 6 Portugal 1995-2007 5. 6 5. 0 0. 0 0. 6 2007-2011-5. 5-4. 9-2. 3 1. 7 Spain 1995-2007 3. 4 0. 5-0. 4 3. 3 2007-2011 3. 3-0. 9 0. 0 4. 3 United kingdom 1995-2007-2. 6-3. 6-0. 2 1. 2 2007-2011-4. 7-6. 0-0. 3 1. 6 USA 1995-2007-2. 4-3. 1 0. 2 0. 5 2007-2011-5. 0-6. 0 0. 7 0. 3 Structural Effects Annualized growth, percentage points 17 Table 1. Changes in World Market Share and Shift-share Decomposition Large Exporters, 1995â 2011 Market Adjusted Share Mkt Share Geography Product Mix Specialized Supplier Industries China 1995-2007 13.0 15.2-1. 4-0. 5 2007-2011 6. 5 7. 3-0. 2-0. 6 France 1995-2007-2. 5-3. 4 0. 5 0. 5 2007-2011-5. 2-4. 3-1. 5 0. 6 Germany 1995-2007-1. 1-2. 2 0. 7 0. 5 2007-2011-2. 5-1. 8-1. 2 0. 5 Italy 1995-2007-1. 5-2. 7 0. 7 0. 5 2007-2011-4. 9-4. 1-1. 3 0. 5 Japan 1995-2007-4. 7-4. 7-0. 3 0. 2 2007-2011-0. 9-2. 5 1. 5 0. 2 Portugal 1995-2007 1. 0 1. 1 0. 1-0. 2 2007-2011-6. 3-3. 2-3. 1-0. 2 Spain 1995-2007-0. 2-0. 5 0. 1 0. 2 2007-2011-4. 8-3. 3-1. 9 0. 3 United kingdom 1995-2007-4. 3-4. 7 0. 1 0. 3 2007-2011-4. 4-3. 2-1. 7 0. 5 USA 1995-2007-3. 4-4. 0 0. 2 0. 5 2007-2011-2. 1-3. 4 0. 8 0. 5 Traditional Industries China 1995-2007 5. 4 8. 6-1. 9-1. 0 2007-2011 3. 4 4. 3-0. 4-0. 4 France 1995-2007-1. 9-2. 6 0. 6 0. 1 2007-2011-3. 5-3. 0-0. 7 0. 2 Germany 1995-2007 0. 1-2. 0 1. 4 0. 8 2007-2011-3. 1-2. 2-0. 2-0. 7 Italy 1995-2007-2. 2-2. 5 0. 5-0. 3 2007-2011-5. 1-4. 4-0. 6-0. 2 Japan 1995-2007-4. 2-4. 7 0. 3 0. 1 2007-2011 0. 4-2. 9 3. 5-0. 1 Portugal 1995-2007-3. 7-4. 0 0. 8-0. 4 2007-2011-1. 5 1. 6-2. 2-0. 9 Spain 1995-2007 0. 7 0. 4 0. 6-0. 3 2007-2011-1. 7-0. 7-0. 5-0. 6 United kingdom 1995-2007-2. 9-4. 5 1. 1 0. 5 2007-2011-5. 3-4. 7-1. 4 0. 7 USA 1995-2007-2. 9-5. 6 1. 8 1. 1 2007-2011-0. 5-2. 1 0. 9 0. 7 Annualized growth, percentage points Structural Effects 18 Table 1. Changes in World Market Share and Shift-share Decomposition Large Exporters, 1995â 2011 (concluded Market Adjusted Share Mkt Share Geography Product Mix Scale-Intensive Technology-Based Industries China 1995-2007 14.6 17.4-2. 4 0. 0 2007-2011 14.3 11.4 1. 4 1. 3 France 1995-2007-2. 3-2. 6 0. 3 0. 0 2007-2011-6. 7-3. 8-2. 7-0. 2 Germany 1995-2007 0. 8 0. 4 0. 4 0. 0 2007-2011-0. 5 1. 1-1. 2-0. 4 Italy 1995-2007-0. 7-0. 1-0. 5 0. 0 2007-2011-5. 7-4. 3-1. 4 0. 0 Japan 1995-2007-3. 1-2. 3-0. 8 0. 1 2007-2011-2. 3-4. 4 2. 3-0. 1 Portugal 1995-2007-0. 2 0. 3-0. 7 0. 1 2007-2011 3. 9 8. 9-4. 1-0. 4 Spain 1995-2007-0. 3 0. 5-0. 9 0. 0 2007-2011-4. 0-2. 1-1. 7-0. 4 United kingdom 1995-2007-0. 7-0. 3-0. 4 0. 0 2007-2011-2. 7-1. 2-1. 2-0. 3 USA 1995-2007-2. 0-3. 0 1. 1-0. 1 2007-2011-0. 3-1. 0 1. 0-0. 2 Scale-Intensive Resource-Based Industries China 1995-2007 8. 2 11.0-2. 2-0. 3 2007-2011 3. 1 4. 3 0. 6-1. 7 France 1995-2007-2. 7-3. 1 0. 2 0. 2 2007-2011-4. 0-2. 1-1. 8-0. 1 Germany 1995-2007-0. 9-1. 4 0. 5-0. 1 2007-2011-2. 4-0. 3-1. 6-0. 5 Italy 1995-2007-0. 8-1. 0 0. 2 0. 0 2007-2011-3. 3-0. 9-1. 7-0. 6 Japan 1995-2007-1. 8-1. 4-0. 7 0. 3 2007-2011 0. 4-1. 2 2. 9-1. 2 Portugal 1995-2007 0. 6 1. 0 0. 7-1. 1 2007-2011 0. 9 3. 9-2. 6-0. 3 Spain 1995-2007 1. 0 1. 5-0. 1-0. 4 2007-2011-1. 3 1. 1-1. 9-0. 6 United kingdom 1995-2007-3. 1-3. 6 0. 1 0. 4 2007-2011-6. 1-4. 7-1. 8 0. 3 USA 1995-2007-2. 5-2. 4 0. 0-0. 1 2007-2011-0. 2-1. 9 1. 1 0. 6 Annualized growth, percentage points Structural Effects Source: IMF Staff calculations using BACI database, developed by Gaulier & Zingano 2010 19 Appendix Shift-Share Analysis and Competitiveness (from ECB, 2012 The method envisages a decomposition of export growth based on a weighted variance analysis (ANOVA) of bilateral export data, disaggregated by product. The methodology is based on Cheptea and others (2005), and seeks to identify the export growth of each exporting country as if all exporters had the same geographical and sectoral specialization With this methodology, âoepureâ exporter performance can be assessed separately from geographical and sectoral effects. The computation of the method consists of four main steps Step 1: Compute midpoint growth rates For a country i exporting a value x to a country c of product k at time t, the midpoint growth rate is defined as follows Ý à oeà à à§à oe Ý à oeà à à§à Ý à oeà à á à§à¿à á 1 2 à Ý à oeà à à§à Ý à oeà à á à§à¿à á à Similarly, the weight attributed to each flow gickt is given by the relative share of the flow in total exports, where total refers to the exports of the whole sample of countries Ý à oeà à à§à oe Ý à oeà à à§à Ý à oeà à á à§à¿à á à âââÝ à oeà à à§à à oeà à âââÝ à oeà à á à§à¿à á à à oeà à The year-on-year growth rate of the total value of world exports is given by summing each individual flow gickt weighted by sickt Step 2: Fixed-effect regression Starting from a bilateral dataset disaggregated by destination and sector (or product), the ANOVA methodology is used to decompose export growth into a sectoral effect, a geographical effect and a pure export competitiveness effect. Specifically, the midpoint growth rate is regressed on three sets of fixed effects, i e.,, exporter, importer and sector/product fixed effects, using weighted OLS. A separate regression is carried out for each year in the data. Hence, if Î is the intercept, Ï is the regression coefficient for exporter fixed effects, Î the one for importer fixed effects, Î the one for product/sector fixed effects and Î the error term, this can be written as Ý Ý Ü¿Ý à oe ß à à ß Ý Ý à à ß Ü à ß Ý Ý à ß In the regression, one exporter i, one importer c and one sector k is omitted to avoid perfect multicollinearity with the constant term Î. This constant term Î corresponds to the export growth of the reference country, and the coefficients should be interpreted as deviations from the performance of this country. In Step 3, however, the effects are normalized so as to quantify them as deviations from the average growth rate of exports for the overall sample in our case, this roughly corresponds to world export growth Step 3: Computation of the indices from the estimated coefficients From the estimated coefficients, growth is decomposed for each exporter (i e.,, aggregating destination and product dimensions. First, however, the coefficients need to be normalized Below, ß à oeà§indicates the performance for exporter i relative to the omitted destination and 20 sector. By contrast, à¤ß à oeà§is the marginal average for iâ s performance independent of the choice of omitted destination. It gives the export growth that country i would have if its geographical and sectoral specialization were equal to the average for the full sample. This is our measure of export performance (competitiveness. This method generates identical results regardless of the choice of the omitted term in the estimation procedure, so that à¤ß à oeà§à oe ß à oeà§à à oeß à oeà§à à Ý à à§ß á à à§à à Ý à à§ß à oeà à §à à This then allows the decomposition of a countryâ s export growth into three components Ý à oeà§à oe à Ý à oeà à à§Ý à oeà à à §à, à à oe à¤ß à oeà§à à Ý à oeà à §Ý à oeà§ß à à à§à à Ý à oeà à §Ý à oeà§ß à¤à à §à à Where ß à à à§à oe ß á à à§à âÝ à ß á à à§à and ß à¤à à§à oe ß à oeà à§à âÝ à ß à oeà à§à. The first component is adjusted the export growth rate, and the second and third components are the geographical and product -mix effects, respectively. The sum of annual growth rates provides the cumulative change over time so that Ý à oeà à à¿à'à à oe à Ý à oeà§à§à oe à à¤ß à oe à §à §à à à Ý à oeà à §Ý à oeà§ß à à à§à à§à à à Ý à oeà à §Ý à oeà§ß à¤à à §à à §The change in export shares is then simply the country-specific growth rate, less the overall growth rate of world trade, and the adjusted export share measure is the country-specific competitiveness measure, less the world growth rate Data The analysis draws from the BACI product-level database developed from COMTRADE data by Gaulier & Zingano (2010), which provides reconciled USD flow figures on more than 200 countries over roughly 5000 products of the Harmonized System (HS classification. Following Cheptea and others (2012), flows below USD10, 000 and those involving micro states are excluded, as are mineral, specific and nonclassified products. For the regressions, 6-digit product data are aggregated down to the 2-digit level Caveats Given the structure of the HS classification, some of the HS 2-digit categories include a very large set of products. This implies that any product mix effects that happen within these very large two-digit categories would be captured by the residual component (adjusted market share) and not by the product-mix component. Also, although the ANOVA-based approach improves on traditional CMSA techniques, it is still the case that the results of this approach may depend on the choice of the selected time-span, or the level of breakdown of the product data 21 References Aghion, P, . and P. Howitt, 2009, âoethe Economics of Growth, â (MIT Press Bank of Italy, 2009, âoereports on Trends in the Italian Productive System, â Occasional Paper No. 45 (Bank of Italy: Rome Bayoumi, T.,J. Turunen, and R. T. Harmsen, 2011, âoeeuro Area Export Performance and Competitiveness, â IMF Working Paper 11/140,(Washington: International Monetary Fund Bayoumi, T.,M. Saito, and J. Turunen, 2013, âoemeasuring Competitiveness: Trade in Goods or Tasks? â IMF Working Paper 13/100,(Washington: International monetary fund Bems, R.,and R c. Johnson, 2012, âoevalue-Added Exchange rates, â NBER Working Paper 18498,(National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc Bogliacino, F, . and M. Pianta, 2010, âoeinnovation and Employment: a Reinvestigation Using Revised Pavitt Classes, â Research Policy, Elsevier, Vol. 39 (6), pp. 799â 809 Bricongne, J.,L. Fontagnã, G. Gaulier, D. Taglioni, and V. Vicard, 2012, âoefirms and the Global Crisis: French Exports in the Turmoil, â Journal of International Economics Elsevier, Vol. 87 (1), pp. 134â 46 Cheptea, A g. Gaulier, and S. Zignago, 2005, âoeworld Trade Competitiveness: A Disaggregated View by Shift-Share Analysis, â Working Paper 2005â 23, CEPII Research Center Cheptea, A l. Fontagnã, and S. Zignago, 2012, âoeeuropean Export Performance, â Working Paper 393,(Banque de france Codogno, L.,2009, âoetwo Italian Puzzles: Are Productivity Growth and Competitiveness Really so Depressed? â Working Paper 2009â 2,(Department of the treasury, Italian Ministry of the Economy and of Finance Crafts, N, . and M. Magnani, 2011, âoethe Golden age and the Second Globalization of Italy, â Quaderni di storia economica (Economic History Working Paper) No. 17,(Bank of Italy Rome Crafts, N.,2012 âoewestern Europeâ s Growth Prospects: A Historical Perspective, â CEPR Discussion Paper 8827 Di Mauro, F.,R. Rà ffer, and I. Bunda, 2008, âoethe Changing Role of the Exchange rate in a Globalised Economy, â Occasional Paper Series, No 94,(European central bank 22 Eichengreen, B.,2011, âoethe Big Cannoli, â Euro Intelligence, October 17, 2011 European central bank, 2012, âoecompetitiveness and External Imbalances within the Euro Area, â Occasional Paper Series 139 The 1994â 2007 Version, â Working papers 2010â 23,(CEPII Research center Gaulier, G.,D. Taglioni, and S. Zignago, 2013, âoeexport Performance in the Wake of the Global Crisis: Evidence from a New Database of Competitiveness Indicatorsâ, mimeo Ginsborg, P.,2003, âoeitaly and Its Discontents: Family, Civil Society, State, â (Palgrave Macmillan Giordano, C. and F. Zollino, 2013, âoethe Divergent Behaviour of Different Competitiveness Indicators for Italy: An Assessment, â Bank of Italy, mimeo Henn, C.,C. Papageorgiou, and N. Spatafora, 2013, âoeexport Quality in Developing Countries, â IMF Working Paper 13/108,(Washington: International monetary fund Kubielas, S.,2007, âoegeographical and Sectoral Pattern of Knowledge Spillovers and Productivity Growth in Polish Industry, â Paper for the DIME Workshop on Agglomeration and Growth in Knowledge-Based Societies, April 20â 21,2007 Ifw: Kiel Leichter, J.,C. Mocci, and S. Pozzuoli, 2011, âoemeasuring External Competitiveness: An Overview, â in Measuring Italyâ s External Competitiveness, ed. by L. Codogno and L. Paganetto,(Rubinetto: Rome Lissovolik, B.,2008, âoetrends in Italy's Non-price Competitiveness, â IMF Working Paper 08/124,(Washington: International monetary fund Manasse, P.,2013, âoethe Roots of the Italian Stagnation, â CEPR Policy Insight No. 66 Centre for Economic policy Research Pavitt, K.,1984, âoesectoral Patterns of Technical Change: Towards a Taxonomy and a Theory, â Research Policy, Elsevier, Vol. 13 (6), pp. 343â 73 Porter, M.,1990, âoethe Competitive Advantage of Nations, â (Free Press: New york
Overtext Web Module V3.0 Alpha
Copyright Semantic-Knowledge, 1994-2011