Research Policy 31 (2002) 735â 747 Innovation, collaboration and SMES internal research capacities Frã dã ric Bougrain a, â, Bernard Haudeville b a CSTB, 4 Avenue du Recteur Poincarã, 75782 Paris Cedex 16, France b CEREFI, Universitã dâ Aix-Marseille III, 13627 Aix-en-Provence Cedex 1, France Accepted 3 july 2001 Abstract The aim of this research paper is to assess how SMES internal research capacities help them to exploit external scientific and technical knowledge and to use networks of innovators. Our empirical analysis draws upon case studies made of projects which were financed partly by ANVAR, a French national agency responsible for the development of innovation projects in industry. The results of this study are threefold â¢Technological co-operation does not seem to increase the chance of success of innovative projects â¢R&d intensity does not lead to discriminate between success and failure â¢Internal R&d capacities, such as a design office, enhance the firmâ s ability to cooperate and to carry its project to success  2002 Elsevier Science B. V. All rights reserved JEL classification: O32 Keywords: Learning process; Industrial co-operation; Internal technological capabilities 1. Introduction Stereotypes usually associate innovation with the work of â a scientist of genius who can propose new combining, go against the tide, show stubborn deter -mination to make his idea successfulâ (Callon, 1994 p. 6). Indeed, innovation and scientific discovery are attributed to individuals. The prizes awarded each year by the Nobel Foundation perfectly illustrate this situation. However, this emblematic picture is misleading. Every scientific and technological break -through results from numerous contributions rather than from individual creations. Successful innova -â Corresponding author. Tel.:++33-1-40-50-29-04 E-mail address: f. bougrain@cstb. fr (F. Bougrain tions appear heavily dependant on trials and errors uncertainty, compromises among several actors The growth of strategic alliances in new core tech -nologies during the 1980s illustrates this situation Hagedoorn, 1995. New interfaces have been created between disciplines (biotechnology plays a growing role in chemical, pharmaceutical, food-processing industries). ) The technological environment within which firms operate has been transformed. Technol -ogy has become so complex that it cannot be handled by individual corporations. Even the biggest compa -nies have been touched by â the declining technical self-sufficiencyâ (Fusfeld, 1986, p. 144. Scientific and technical knowledge is scattered among a large number of people. Its acquisition needs to rely on groups which interact through networks 0048-7333/02/$ â see front matter  2002 Elsevier Science B. V. All rights reserved PII: S0 0 4 8-7333 (01) 00144-5 736 F. Bougrain, B. Haudeville/Research Policy 31 (2002) 735â 747 All firms have been affected by this technologi -cal challenge. Even small firms which performs R&d have been engaged in co-operation (Kleinknecht and Reijnen, 1992 In most OECD s countries, this tendency has been reinforced by public authorities who prefer to favour inter-firm co-operation rather than to provide direct financial assistance Public sectors interventions are threefold â¢Public authorities have laid increasing emphasis on inter-firm collaboration in advanced technology Most of the time these programmes urge large firms located in the same geographical area to cooperate e g. the Esprit and Alvey programmes in the European union. They also tend to focus on prec -ompetitive research activities (Fusfeld, 1986. This policy has been influenced by similar successful alliances in the Japanese computer industry â¢The success of co-operation among small tradi -tional firms in Italy has inspired regional initiatives Rosenfeld, 1996. Public authorities have tried to recreate the Italian district atmosphere by providing new services and by fostering technology transfer â¢The success of networks in the Silicon valley has led to the development of science parks/technopole which involve universities, public R&d laboratories and firms. The aim of this policy is to enhance the innovative capability of the host region by strength -ening the ties among scientific, technical and insti -tutional agents. Unlike policies inspired by Italian districts, universities and research institutions in -volvements are stronger. 1 In spite of these initiatives, one must not forget that cooperative agreements are based on technology transfers which imply the respect of economic rules The challenge is particularly delicate for SMES. Those who establish weak ties with their environment may not favourably react to public policies which emphasis on inter-firm collaboration. Conversely, firms engaged in a virtuous process to acquire technological com -1 In France, different levels of public authorities are engaged in these policies. The European community and The french central government lead the large projects. The institutional infrastructure built to promote regional co-operation was initiated by the cen -tral government. But its implementation is a matter for regional authorities. Finally, the technopolitan movement was launched by local authorities petencies should benefit from the policy orientations Le Bas, 1993 In the present paper, we report how firmsâ inter -nal capacities generate this virtuous process. We will draw upon case studies made of projects which were carried out by about 300 SMES, from 1980 to 1987 We will focus on firms which cooperate with other organisations. Before this empirical study, we will describe the notion of networks and discuss their role in innovation. Then, we will examine the role of the manager in the innovation process. Indeed, man -agers play a key role in the running of their business Depending on their risk adversity, they will innovate and exploit networks information differently 2. Industrial co-operation: from exchange to production From a theoretical point of view, the notion of net -work is still very fuzzy. However, we can distinguish at least following two approaches â¢The transaction cost perspective identifies networks as an intermediate governance structure between markets and hierarchies. In this perspective, tech -nology is dissociated from production which is secondary â¢The evolutionary theory considers that technology acquires its specific character through a learning process. In this perspective, we should place em -phasis on the production activity 2. 1. Limits of the transaction cost theory According to Williamson, asset specificity, uncer -tainty, the frequency with which transactions recur bounded rationality and opportunism determine which governance structure is adapted best to manage trans -action (Williamson, 1989 Low asset specificity favours competitive bargains and leads to contractual solutions. To explain the emergence of networks (the hybrid form between markets and hierarchies), Williamson puts forward the existence of strong property rights combined with intermediary asset specificity. However markets and hybrid forms are adapted not always. When agents have to support durable investment, competition is transformed into a bilateral transaction. In such a situation, vertical integration is adapted best to avoid F. Bougrain, B. Haudeville/Research Policy 31 (2002) 735â 747 737 opportunistic behaviours. This decision is considered as a choice of last resort (â try markets, try long-term contracts and other hybrid modes, and revert to hi -erarchy only for compelling reasonsâ (Williamson 1991, p. 83 Notwithstanding the interest of this approach to pro -vide an analytical scheme for the study of networks several limits remain â¢The primary goal of this theory is to know whether a firm should make or buy a good or a service. In this framework, firm and market are considered as perfect substitute. This situation derives from the assumption that information is costly for transac -tion purpose but not for production purpose (Dem -setz, 1991. If one considers that the acquisition of information is costly, firms will not bear the same production costs. So it â might be in the interest of a firm to produce its own inputs even if transac -tion costs were zero and management costs were positiveâ (Demsetz, 1991, p. 164 Considering that technology is costly to produce also reverses the transactional approach. According to this theory, armâ s length agreements for technol -ogy transfer are costly. First, agents are engaged in negotiations to define the terms of the contract Once the agreement is signed, they will under -take inspection to make sure that their partner is not shirking. Given these assumptions on oppor -tunistic behaviours, transaction costs should reach prohibitive levels when innovation is involved However, this is not the case. In fact, negotiations which lead up to a bargain should not be considered as a cost but as an investment (Everaere, 1993 Agents rely on this process to learn about their mutual needs and to make decision to avoid bottle -necks during the implementation of the project â¢The transactional approach puts too much em -phasis on opportunism. However, â an organisation should be understood at least much as a mecha -nism to enhance co-operation than as a device to reduce cheating and shirkingâ (Mà nard, 1992. By and large recurrent transactions lead partners in -volved in a network to gradually trust one another These collaborative relationships entail learning Lundvall, 1993 â¢As one of the â four contemporary paradigms in the Theory of the Firmâ described by Winter (1991 p. 187), transaction cost theory is first and fore -most a matter of exchange and bounded rationality Production is secondary. Consequently, it fails to â examine how new resource uses are discovered how resources are accumulated, how firms learn which governance structures best promote learning etc. â (Foss, 1996, p. 12 2. 2. Co-operation as a learning process Knowledge for production purpose cannot be con -sidered as free. The role of the firm is not to allocate costless technical competencies (Pelikan, 1988). 2 They have to set them up. These competencies change over time through a learning process and become tacit and specific to the firm (Foss, 1996. This change has crucial consequences for firmsâ performances and economic organisations â¢The tacitness of competencies make them diffi -cult to imitate. Therefore, firmsâ endowments in technical capacities are not similar. Once they are built, they provide the firm with a competitive advantage. 3 â¢The process of knowledge creation is costly to main -tain. Therefore, firms need to achieve economies through specialisation (Demsetz, 1991. This may explains why firms usually prefer to concentrate their resources toward core activities. To obtain complementary assets, two solutions are possible Market transaction or co-operation. However, tac -itness and specificity impede the completion of technology transfer. 4 Thus, firms cannot rely on market to have access to new capabilities Cooperative agreements are adapted when firms are reluctant to develop additional capacities but need 2 Pelikan considers that â technical competence is the compe -tence for designing products and production processes in terms of physical variables, and includes also the competence to learn such competence, or technical talentsâ (Pelikan, 1988, p. 383. Follow -ing this definition, we regard knowledge as a mean to enhance technical competence 3 â...The concept of the organisational capabilities that permit it (the firm) to remain competitive, and therefore profitable, in national and international markets (is) more pertinent than those of bounded rationality and opportunismâ (Chandler, 1992, p. 490 4 â Know-how has a strong learning-by-doing character, and it may be essential that human capital in an effective team configu -ration accompany the transferâ (Teece, 1980, p. 228 738 F. Bougrain, B. Haudeville/Research Policy 31 (2002) 735â 747 to have access to closely complementary and dis -similar activities (Richardson, 1972. It is sought when ex ante co-ordination between different phases of production is necessary. Despite production and transaction costs, firms should not be reluctant to pur -sue a strategy of cooperative agreements for at least following two reasons â¢Considering that firms are endowed not equally with technical competence but need to construct them, in -creases the financial constraints which firms bear. In this scheme, investment costs are dissociated from receipts (Amendola and Gaffard, 1994. Thus, it takes time to recover the initial investment. Collab -orative relationships will release the financial con -straints by helping the firm to share the sunk costs associated with innovation â¢The second reason relates to learning. Collaborative relationships might take a hierarchical form. How -ever, when trust replaces uncertainty and oppor -tunism, informal obligations may constitute a more stable framework for interaction (Lundvall, 1988 This is possible if firms consider that the future is more significant than the present (Jacquemin, 1987 In the case of userâ producer relations, the frequency of interactive relationships have proved to speed up the innovation process. Indeed, frequent commu -nications help them to specify their mutual needs In this case, unlike the transaction cost theory, re -current transactions favour cooperative agreement This interactive learning has following three dimen -sions (Lundvall, 1993 â Technical learning exists when interaction be -tween users and producers induces an under -standing of reciprocal needs â Communicative learning involves the establish -ment of technical codes, tacit and specific to the partners â Social learning limits opportunism by creating similar behavioural codes The access to external linkages is assumed to be crucial for SMES competitiveness 3. SMES and external communication SMES tend to be less innovative than large compa -nies and to dedicate less resources to the acquisition of external technologies. In France, from 1990 to 1992 30.5%of firms with a number of employees ranging from 20 to 49, were considered as innovators and 93 %of those with more than 2000 employees were engaged in this process (SESSI, 1996. These results do not mean that SMES are less efficient than big firms. 5 The absence of hierarchical levels and horizontal commu -nications favours quick reaction to keep abreast with environmental disturbances and fast changing market requirements In fact, what distinguishes SMES in comparison with large companies is not in that they have a lower turnover or a smaller size. The crucial point is that they are managed usually by their owners 3. 1. The crucial role of the manager during the innovation process In SMES, the manager bears the responsibility of taking the decisions regarding all aspects of technical change. Thus, risk adversity may impede the innova -tion process. Following two types of behaviour are usually applicable to managers (OCDE, 1993 â¢In the first category, one finds managers who look for the stability of their company and consider that innovation represents a large financial risk. So they only innovate under the pressure of their environ -ment. They limit their contacts with the external environment to suppliers and clients. The manage -ment style is centralised â¢The second kind of entrepreneurial managers en -courage rapid growth of their company. They ac -cept risk and try to take advantages of every new opportunity. To enhance the performance and the growth of their company, they forge external tech -nical and scientific linkages with educational es -tablishments, research associations and other public agencies. They know that the success of their com -pany is based on the quality of their employees and on their commitments to networks of innovators. In this prospect, the managersâ educational level in -fluences the scope of the network. Highly educated 5 The survey carried out by the SPRU revealed that from 1945 to 1980, SMES highly contributed to innovation. Their share in innovation was higher than their share in total formal R&d (Roth -well and Zegveld, 1982 F. Bougrain, B. Haudeville/Research Policy 31 (2002) 735â 747 739 managers tend to rely more on research and advi -sory agencies and less on informal contacts 3. 2. The role of networks in SMES competitiveness Firms which benefit from interpersonal contacts through networks will gain following three kinds of competitive advantages â¢Information is the nerve of competition which sets up among firms. Nevertheless, the complexity of information makes it more difficult to master. Be -cause of their lack of financial resources, SMES are often disadvantaged in their ability to gather tech -nical information of paramount importance (Julien 1994). ) Vis-Ã-vis large firms, they suffer from an in -formation gap. Networks allow SMES to decode and appropriate flows of information. They reinforce SMES competitiveness by providing them with a window on technological change, sources of tech -nical assistance, market requirements and strategic choices made by other firms â¢Tacit knowledge is very important in innovation Senker, 1995. This knowledge cannot be trans -ferred through written documents. 6 It is embodied in the personal knowledge of technical and scien -tific agents. Therefore, personal networks which favour acquaintances become the main channel for its transfer. To know who holds information is cru -cial when one faces complex technological issues Members of networks â provide the know-why know-how, know-when, and know-what necessary for entrepreneurial successâ (Malecki and Tootle 1996, p. 45 â¢Innovation is characterised by its uncertainty. Firms need to raise financial means as soon as they launch research projects. Conversely, results are uncertain and remote. Ten years can elapse between research and commercialisation. As time passes, resources become more specific. This augments the irre -versibility of the firmâ s commitment. Moreover in many fields, where technical changes are rapid and product life cycle very short, the acquisition of technology through traditional means (licence 6 â In each technology there are elements of tacit and specific knowledge that are not and cannot be written down in a â blueprintâ form, and cannot, therefore, be diffused entirely either in the form of public or proprietary informationâ (Dosi, 1988, p. 1131 agreement) turns out to be risky and subject to obsolescence. By using either formal or informal networks, SMES reduce their irreversibility costs 7 and have access to new knowledge To assess how cooperative R&d foster the suc -cess of innovative projects, we draw upon case studies made of projects which were launched by small busi -ness enterprises of the Centre region (around the Loire Valley 4. Impact of cooperative relationships on successful innovation: analysis from a panel of French SMES 4. 1. Research methodology The firms of our sample received public funds to partly finance their innovative activities. These funds were allocated by ANVAR, a French national agency responsible for the development of innovation projects in industry. The regional agencies, located everywhere in France, aid small firms not only through financial assistance, 8 but also through technological advice Therefore, they play a key role in the existence of re -gional networks consisting of firms, academic institu -tions and government agencies We ground our study on 313 projects (247 enter -prises) which were financed partly by the agency lo -cated in Orlã ans from 1980 to 1987. By selecting projects which were launched between 1980 and 1987 we wanted to be able to judge whether the firms had achieved their technological and commercial goals. In 1995, at the time of our inquiry, the results of each innovative projects were known just for the period 1980â 1987 Our analysis is a comparison of the ways in which success differ from failures. We estimated a logistic 7 According to Foray (1991), cooperative R&d can take various organisational forms. It goes from internal to contractual research Along this axis, resources are less specific but reversibility is stronger 8 The financial assistance can cover up to 50%of the costs of the innovation project. The firms refund the agency only in case of success and without paying any interest. Large firm are usually excluded from this procedure. In France, about 5%of firms with more than 500 employees benefited from the financial aid 740 F. Bougrain, B. Haudeville/Research Policy 31 (2002) 735â 747 regression model, with the dependant variable, the re -sult of the innovative project, defined equal to 1 if the firm refunded ANVAR without notifying any technical problems to the agency, and equal to 0 if the project is a failure. The independent variables are the categories of firms, the sector of production of the innovation and the technical partners The categories of the firms: the enterprises were classified into eight categories depending on their size and their ownership status (Appendix A). These firms are supposed not to be representative of the population of French SMES. If a firm asks for the assistance of the agency, it proves that it innovates and is open to its institutional environment 4. 1. 1. The sector of production of the innovation The innovative projects were classified according to The french Industrial Classification of Products and Activities (NAF 16)( SESSI, 1995. We added five categories to this nomenclature: food-processing industry, software industry, building industry and agriculture. The projects which did not fit into this classification belong to the â otherâ category. The dis -tribution of projects according to the size of the firm the ownership status and the sectors of production of the innovations are presented in Table 1 4. 1. 2. The technical partners Some SMES worked on their innovation project by relying exclusively on their internal competencies Other collaborated both on formal and informal basis Table 1 Distribution of projects according to firm size, ownership status and the sectors of production of the innovations (NAF 16 Size and status of firms Employees Regional group Subsidiary of group Totala Sectors 1â 9 10â 19 20â 49 50â 99 100â 250 251â 499 Consumer goods 5 3 3 6 5 1 0 1 24 (7. 7 Automobile 2 0 0 1 3 2 1 2 11 (3. 5 Capital goods 29 17 37 20 19 4 10 12 148 (47.3 Intermediate goods 10 4 13 9 9 6 1 22 74 (23.6 Food processing 1 1 1 0 3 2 8 2 18 (5. 7 Agriculture 3 0 3 2 0 0 0 0 8 (2. 6 Construction 2 1 1 0 3 0 1 0 8 (2. 6 Computing activities 1 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 (1 Other 2 2 7 1 2 2 1 2 19 (6. 1 Total 55 30 65 39 44 17 18 45 313 Percentages 17.6 9. 6 20.8 12.5 14.0 5. 4 5. 7 14.4 100 a The values shown in the parenthesis are in percentages Several technical partners were identified: clients suppliers, other firms (than clients and suppliers professional and technical centres, educational insti -tutions (university, engineering school, technical col -lege), research institutions (CNRS, INRA, INSERM and CEA. Individual inventors and designers are the â other partnersâ (Table 2 In Table 2, we report following three different models â¢The first tests the effect of cooperative relation -ships as a whole. One of the dependant variable is collaboration. It is equal to 1 if the firm relied on external competencies, and equal to 0 if the firm did not cooperate with external partners â¢The second tests the role of the partners which were approached by the firms for technical purposes â¢The last model only keeps the variables which were the most significant in models 1 and 2, in predicting the results of the innovative projects However, our approach is not exhaustive. It does not show how SMES are linked to networks 4. 2. The role of linkages to external resources The success rate of small and medium enterprises which obtained external knowledge from other com -panies or from public research institutions through technological co-operation, was higher (Table 3 However, from the results of our estimating procedure Table 2, model 1), we cannot say that technological F. Bougrain, B. Haudeville/Research Policy 31 (2002) 735â 747 741 Table 2 Logistic regression of the likelihood of success of innovative projects Dependant variable: success of innovative projects Name of the explanatory variables Coefficient (t of Student model 1 Coefficient (t of Student model 2 Coefficient (t of Student model 3 Constant â'0. 3033 (â'0. 685) 0. 3701 (0. 877) 0. 3554 (1. 496 Categories of firms Very small enterprises 1â 9 employees â'0. 9152â (â'1. 938) â'1. 2468â â (â'2. 536) â'1. 1226â â (â'2. 936 Very small enterprises 10â 19 employees 0. 240 (0. 487) 0. 216 (0. 415) â SME (20â 49 employees) 0. 1231 (0. 296) â'0. 2114 (â'0. 485) â SME (50â 99 employees) 0. 9406â (2. 002) 0. 7647 (1. 551) 0. 8808â (2. 304 SME (100â 250 employees) â'0. 1773 (â'0. 395) â'0. 3186 (â'0. 667) â SME (251â 499 employees) â'0. 4788 (â'0. 763) â'0. 9574 (â'1. 473) â'0. 7976 (â '1. 388 Regional group 0. 9187 (1. 457) 0. 9871 (1. 484) 1. 1564â (2. 090 Subsidiaries Reference Reference â Sectors of production of the innovations Consumer goods industry 0. 123 (0. 244) 0. 257 (0. 479 Automobile industry â'1. 2997 (â'1. 531) â'1. 6095+(â'1. 827) â'1. 7413â (â'2. 050 Capital goods industry â'0. 4124 (â'1. 324) â'0. 3416 (â'1. 049) â'0. 4722+(â'1. 829 Food processing industry â'1. 9053+(â'1. 677) â'1. 7642 (â'1. 489) â'1. 83 (â'1. 591 Agriculture â'0. 1699 (â'0. 282) 0. 3457 (0. 526) â Other â'0. 473 (â'0. 103) 0. 4377 (0. 009) â Intermediate goods industry Reference Reference â Cooperative relationships 0. 196 (0. 616) â â Partners Supplier â â'0. 9202â â (â'2. 826) â'0. 8627â â (â'2. 709 Client â â'0. 1145 (â'0. 408) â Enterprise â â'0. 5025 (â'1. 629) â'0. 4138 (â'1. 392 Technical centre â 0. 3034 (0. 936) â Engineering and technical school/university â 0. 213 (0. 587) â National research centre â â'1. 9709â â (â'3. 096) â'1. 8226â â (â'2. 997 Other partners â â'0. 0886 (â'0. 180) â n 313 313 313 Log likelihood â'195.9618 â'185.3175 â'186.8962 Prediction with the logic Prediction Observations Prediction %Failures Success Model 1 Failures 156 30 186 83.9 Success 80 47 127 37.0 Total 236 77 313 64.9 Model 2 Failures 141 45 186 75.8 Success 60 67 127 52.8 Total 201 112 313 66.4 742 F. Bougrain, B. Haudeville/Research Policy 31 (2002) 735â 747 Table 2 (Continued Prediction with the logic Prediction Observations Prediction %Failures Success Model 3 Failures 153 33 186 82.2 Success 73 54 127 42.5 Total 226 87 313 66.1 +Significant at 10 %â Significant at 5 %â â Significant at 1 %Table 3 Links between cooperative relationships and innovation projectsa Success Success rate Failures Failure rate Number of projects Technological partnerships 109 42.2 149 57.8 258 Number of technological partnerships 18 32.7 37 67.3 55 Number of projects 127 40.6 186 59.4 313 a According to the Ï 2-test, there is no direct link between the result of a project and technological partnerships co-operation increases the chance of success of inno -vative projects As can be seen the predictive performance of suc -cess is increased when the categories of collaborations are separated. Surprisingly, the two categories which appear significant affect negatively the results of the projects. Cooperative agreements with suppliers and research institutions decrease significantly the chances of success. 9 However, we cannot cast doubt over policies which tend to establish partnerships between SMES and other institutions. The failure of a project does not mean that SMES would have done better by relying on their own capabilities. The weaknesses of our study are threefold â¢Firstly, we lack qualitative information about the nature of the ties instituted between SMES and their partners. Developing mutual trust implies the es -tablishment of common codes of information. This 9 The size affects negatively the results of the innovative projects only for very small enterprises (less than 10 employees. For extensive results on the relation between firm size and innovation and on cooperative relationships between SMES and research institutions, see Bougrain (2000 process takes time before being effective (Lundvall 1988 â¢Secondly, this analysis comes up against the way to apprehend informal relationships. All cooperative projects between customers and suppliers do not always lead to payment in full. This is the case when a customer tests for free the new product of his supplier. In such a situation, informal exchange may not have appeared in the progress report of the project. Thus, we probably underestimated the customerâ supplier relations. 10 This lack of infor -mation is problematic because of the importance of informal interactions to transfer tacit knowledge. 11 â¢Finally, to analyse if cooperative relationships are effective, we cannot assume that SMES adopt a pas -sive behaviour vis-Ã-vis their partners. Indeed, an upsurge of cooperative R&d agreements has been noticed in recent years. However, this increase did 10 In his study, Hagedoorn drew similar conclusions (1995 11 According to Von Hippel, informal know-how trading is very active when â (1) the needed know-how exists in the hands of some member of the trading network, and when (2) the know-how is proprietary only by virtue of its secrecy, and when (3) the value of a particular traded module is too small to justify an explicit negotiated agreement to sell, license or exchangeâ (Von Hippel 1987, p. 300 F. Bougrain, B. Haudeville/Research Policy 31 (2002) 735â 747 743 not indicate that collective research was a substitute for corporate research. Both were complementary Mowery, 1983 So we need to examine how firmsâ internal research capacities help them to exploit external scientific and technical knowledge 5. Relationships between firms internal capabilities and successful innovations 5. 1. Relation between absorptive capacity and external learning Firms do not delegate their research activities to other industrial corporations. To keep initiative and technical leadership, they need to strengthen their in-house research facilities According to Cohen and Levinthal (1989), innova -tive capabilities depend on the ability to exploit exter -nal knowledge and on in-house R&d efforts. These arguments reverse Arrowâ s analytical framework who considered that firms underinvest in R&d because im -itation costs are smaller than the cost of creating new knowledge. If â these costs are relatively small, it is by virtue of the considerable R&d already conducted by the firms in the vicinity of the emissionâ (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989, p. 570 Firmsâ ability to develop an absorptive capacity heavily depends on investment made during previous periods. These initial investments allow them to make better technological choices and to exploit new oppor -tunities better. If a firm temporarily neglects to invest in a technical field, it will be less aware of techno -logical opportunities (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990. So it will increase its initial weakness. To maintain their potential competitiveness, firms need to have at least a window on state-of-the-art technologies Communication systems also play a great role to in -crease organisational absorptive capacity. Firms must focus both on the interface between the departments and the external environment and on horizontal com -munication among departments. Overlapping knowl -edge across individuals is crucial to ameliorate internal transfer while diversity of knowledge elicit â learning and problem solving that yields innovationâ (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990, p. 133 According to this theoretical scheme, firmsâ ability to exploit external knowledge depends on their ab -sorptive capacity. Consequently, we cannot consider that an analysis of the link between collaborative rela -tionships and innovation is adequate. We need to take into account internal factors which would improve the learning capacity and contribute to the success of cooperative projects. Following three factors which characterised in-house innovative capabilities will be analysed â¢R&d intensity â¢the number of executives employed by the firm â¢and the existence of a design office We did not take into account all the above-mentioned projects (313. We restrained our survey to SMES which were involved in a cooperative agreement Moreover we dismissed many projects because data were not fully available for each case. From 1980 to 1987, ANVAR changed its administrative forms. Thus, along the period, information con -cerning the firms were not homogeneous and rather limited Information related to the existence of a design office was available in 91 cases. We decided not to take into account the percentage of executives to employees for SMES with less than 10 employ -ees. We thought that these figures would not have been significant. Consequently, we just relied on 83 projects. R&d intensity was available for 79 files Due to the limited sample size, we only estimated basic logistic regression models and we performed a Ï 2-test for the three factors which characterised in-house innovative capabilities 5. 2. Links between R&d intensity and successful innovation According to our regression 1 (Table 4) and to the Ï 2-test (Table 5), R&d intensity does not influence future prospects of a project. These results based on a small sample, confirm those of Rocha (1999, p. 268 He considered that greater R&d intensity is not nec -essary when firms need â to absorb external knowledge produced through inter-firm alliancesâ However, our research methodology may ex -plain these results. Production, diffusion and use of 744 F. Bougrain, B. Haudeville/Research Policy 31 (2002) 735â 747 Table 4 Logistic regression of the likelihood of success of innovative projects Dependant variable: success of innovative projects Name of the explanatory variables Coefficient (t of Student model 1 Coefficient (t of Student model 2 Coefficient (t of Student model 3 Constant 0. 0791 (â'0. 389) 0. 1321 (0. 347) â'0. 469+(â'1. 7997 Research intensity â'0. 0208 (â'0. 176 Size (number of employees) â'0. 00018 (0. 861 Executives(%)â'1. 3198 (â'0. 431 Design office 0. 045+(0. 088 n 79 83 91 Log likelihood â'53.279 â'185.3175 â'186.8962 +Significant at 10 %Table 5 Links between R&d intensitya and results of cooperative projectsb Projects results R&d intensity Success Success rate Failures Failure rate Number of projects Weak (less than 1%of sales) 10 43.5 13 56.5 23 Middle (between 1 and 4%of sales) 13 44.8 16 55.2 29 Strong (more than 4%of sales) 15 55.6 12 44.4 27 Number of projects 38 48.1 41 51.9 79 a These three classes of R&d intensity fit the recommendations advocated by the OCDE (1992. Firms which dedicate less than 1 %of their turnover to R&d, belong to the class of weak research intensity b According to the Ï 2-test, there is no direct link between the result of a project and R&d intensity innovation are different among sectors (Pavitt, 1984 However, to analyse the correlation between R&d intensity and projects results, we do not take into ac -count the sectoral patterns of innovation. In high-tech sectors, a regime of fast technological change squeezes the firms to devote more resources to R&d. In the textile industry, technological constraints are not so strong Despite this drawback, our results tend to confirm that R&d intensity cannot be considered as a perfect indicator to measure the innovative activity which is performed in SMES. Following two elements argue in this way â¢The main problem is to know which expendi -tures firms include in R&d. In France, firms may announce the figures which they declare to benefit from research tax deduction. But the appropriateness of the definition used by the fiscal administration to determine R&d ex -penditures, is criticised (Lhuillery and Templã 1995 â¢R&d is only one source of innovation. 12 This remark applies particularly to SMES. Their re -search activities are not as formal and organised as in large firms. 13 SMES may carry out their R&d activities â without a formal R&d department or a formal budget and often even outside regu -lar working hoursâ (Kleinknecht, 1989, p. 216 Consequently, it is difficult to identify R&d invest -ments of small firms (Roper, 1998. This indicator cannot be satisfactory to analyse SMES ability to innovate 12 â Whilst working on definitions and measurement of research and development in the 1960s one frequently encountered the view that what should be measured in industry was not R&d, but R, D&dâ Research, Design and Developmentâ (Freeman, 1992 p. 50 13 â We have shown that when we treat technical change as syn -onymous with R&d activities in science-based industries, we are in danger of neglecting up to nearly 40%of what is going on in technical change, especially in non-electrical machinery and in small firmsâ (Patel and Pavitt, 1994, p. 543 F. Bougrain, B. Haudeville/Research Policy 31 (2002) 735â 747 745 Table 6 Influence of executives presence on success rate of cooperative projectsa Project result %of executives to employees Success Success rate Failures Failure rate Number of projects From 0 to 5 9 42.9 12 57.1 21 From 5. 01 to 9 15 55.6 12 44.4 27 â ¥9. 01 19 54.3 16 45.7 35 Number of projects 43 51.8 40 48.2 83 a According to the Ï 2-test, there is no direct link between the result of a project and the percentages of executives to employees 5. 3. The contribution of executives to successful collaborative relationships The presence of executives indicates that the en -trepreneurial manager delegates part of his power to its subordinates. So, he can spend more time to run effec -tively his business and to formulate strategic plans for technological development. Consequently, the pres -ence of executives should increase the success rate of innovation. Our empirical results invalidate what we expected. According to regression 2 (Table 4) and to the Ï 2-test (Table 6), there is not a direct link between the result of a cooperative project and the percentages of executives to employees. Following three elements may explain why collaborative relationships are not more successful when the percentage of executives to employees is larger â¢This category is heterogeneous. Research and pro -duction managers are often at the heart of the innovation process. Similarly, sales managers will enhance the firmâ s ability to respond to prospects of the market. Conversely, accountants and other administrative executives do not play a key role during the innovative activity. In other words, the percentage of executives is only quantitative. It does not give any information on the organisational efficiency of the firms (Perrin, 1991 â¢We would also need information about executivesâ educational qualification. This lack of qualitative information is problematic. Indeed, the level of ed -ucation influences the receptiveness of executives to external sources and their approach to innova -tion problems to a considerable extent (Gibbons and Johnston, 1974. When executives with a high level of education are confronted to a complex problem they recognise if the firm can rely on its own competencies to resolve this problem. If the firmâ s capabilities are not sufficient they know who to contact. Conversely, the staff with a lower level of education relies more on their own knowledge â¢In firms, innovative competencies do not depend exclusively on executive staff. Technicians are also crucial actors of product/process innovations in SMES. They differently conceive the innovative ac -tivity but they contribute to incremental innovations as well as executives 5. 4. The contribution of design office to successful collaborative relationships The activity of a design office is not as formal as in a R&d department. It is orientated more toward the development and improvement of existing products than radical innovation. The design office is composed of engineers and technicians. It gives a better picture of the innovative activities in SMES. Sometimes in the smallest firms, engineers are not even present. Some entrepreneurial managers are reluctant to commit their projects to engineers because they fear their high level of education Firms who are endowed with this office have already structured their innovative capabilities. They rely less on informal knowledge. This explain why the success of collective innovation is correlated to the existence of the design office (Tables 4 and 7). Thanks to this of -fice SMES partners know better who to inform in case of technical problems. We also assume that qualified employees working there are more able to understand information flowing through industrial networks These results are in conformity with the assertion of Cohen and Levinthal (1989, p. 569) who suggested that â while R&d obviously generates innovations it also develops the firmâ s â learningâ or â absorptiveâ capacityâ 746 F. Bougrain, B. Haudeville/Research Policy 31 (2002) 735â 747 Table 7 Links between design office and success rate of cooperative projectsa Project result structure of SMES Success Success rate Failures Failure rate Number of projects Presence of a design office 36 50.7 35 49.3 71 No design office 5 25 15 75 20 Number of projects 41 45.1 50 54.9 91 a According to the Ï 2-test, there is a direct link between the result of a project and the presence of a design office at 90%level Internal expertise facilitates the identification of ex -ternal information, their absorption and the improve -ment of SMES performances. If a decoding does not happen, the assimilation of external knowledge to the firmâ s â technological capitalâ (Le Bas and Zuscovitch 1993, p. 185) will not be effective 6. Conclusion We know that SMES are increasingly dependent on external sources of technical activity because the pro -cess which generates new technologies is becoming more complex. However, before having access to the knowledge held by competencies centres, SMES need to develop and structure their own capacities. One way to achieve this goal is to hire technically qualified manpower Indeed, our results show that a design office facili -tates the use of extensive information networks. Firms with no design office do not master the innovation process well. They experience difficulties not only to consult the appropriate source of information but also to get access to existing networks and to appropriate state-of-the-art technologies. Without this office col -laborative relationships are riskier and not as effective Acknowledgements A preliminary version of this paper was presented at the International Workshop on Innovation, SMES and Local Development in Cremona, Italy. Some results were discussed also at the seminars at the Universities of Orlã ans (LEO) and Strasbourg (BETA. We are in -debted to all participants. We are also grateful to the people who work at the ANVAR regional agency lo -cated in Orlã ans Appendix A The enterprises were classified into eight categories depending on their size and their ownership status. Our classification is more detailed than the recommenda -tions of the OECD (1992. The firms with between 1 and 9, 10 and 19,20 and 49,50 and 99,100 and 250 251 and 499 employees were all independent The other categories concern large enterprises and subsidiaries. We distinguish regional groups with more than 500 employees whose headquarters is located in the Centre region and subsidiaries of company whose group employment exceeds 500 employees and is lo -cated outside the Centre region By holding concurrently two criteria, the size of the firm and the ownership status, we avoid the classifica -tion discrepancies described by Tether et al. 1997 References Amendola, M.,Gaffard, J.-L.,1994. Markets and organisations as coherent systems of innovation. Research Policy 23, 627â 635 Bougrain, F.,2000. Les P m. E. et lâ innovation: implications en matiã re de politique technologique rã gionaleâ Cas de la rã gion Centre et comparaison avec le Bade-Wurtemberg. Ph d. thesis unpublished), Laboratoire dâ Economie dâ Orlã ans, Universitã dâ Orlã ans Callon, M.,1994. Lâ innovation technologique et ses mythes Annales des Mines Gà rer et Comprendre 3, 5â 17 Chandler, A d.,1992. What is a firm? A historical perspective European Economic Review 36, 483â 494 Cohen, W. M.,Levinthal, D. A.,1989. Innovation and learning: the two faces of R&d. The Economic Journal 99 (9), 569â 596 Cohen, W. M.,Levinthal, D. A.,1990. Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning innovation. Administrative Science Quaterly 35 (3), 128â 152 Demsetz, H.,1991. The theory of the firm revisited. In: Williamson O. E.,Winter, S g. Eds. The Nature of the Firm. Oxford University Press, New york, pp. 159â 178 Dosi, G.,1988. Sources, procedures, and microeconomic effects of innovation. Journal of Economic Literature 26, 1120â 1171 F. Bougrain, B. Haudeville/Research Policy 31 (2002) 735â 747 747 Everaere, C.,1993. Des coã ts aux investissements de transaction Pour un renversement de la thã orie de Williamson. Revue Franã§aise dâ Economie 8 (Summer), 149â 203 Foray, D.,1991. Repã res pour une à conomie des organisations de recherche-dã veloppement. Revue dâ Economie Politique 101 779â 808 Foss, N. J.,1996. Capabilities the theory of the firm. Revue dâ Economie Industrielle 77 (3), 7â 28 Freeman C.,1992. The Economics of Hope. Pinter Publishers London Fusfeld, H. I.,1986. The Technical Enterprise. Ballinger Publishing Cambridge, MA Gibbons, M.,Johnston, R.,1974. The roles of science in technological innovation. Research Policy 3, 221â 242 Hagedoorn, J.,1995. Strategic technology partnering during the 1980s: trends, networks and corporate patterns in non-core technologies. Research Policy 24, 207â 231 Jacquemin, A.,1987. Comportements collusifs et accords en recherche-dã veloppement. Revue dâ Economie Politique 97, 1â 23 Julien, P. A.,1994. Les P m. E.:Bilan et Perspectives. Economica Paris Kleinknecht, A.,1989. Firm size and innovation. Small Business Economics 1, 215â 222 Kleinknecht, A.,Reijnen, J. O. N.,1992. Why do firms cooperate on R&d? An empirical study. Research Policy 21, 347â 360 Le Bas, C.,1993. Le comportement dâ investissement en ressources technologiques externes et lâ absorption technologique dans les moyennes entreprises industrielles. Revue Internationale des P m. E. 6, 35â 64 Le Bas, C.,Zuscovitch, E.,1993. Apprentissage technologique et organisation: une analyse des configurations micro -à conomiques. Economies et Sociã tã s 27 (5), 153â 195 Lhuillery, S.,Templã, P.,1995. Lâ impact du C i. R. sur lâ innovation dans les entreprises. In: Haudeville, B.,Hà raud, J.-A Humbert, M. Eds. Technologie et Performances à conomiques Economica, Paris, pp. 155â 182 Lundvall, B.-A.,1988. Innovation as an interactive process: from userâ producer interaction to the national system of innovation In: Dosi, G.,Freeman, C.,Nelson, R.,Silverberg, G.,Soete L. Eds. Technical Change and Economic theory. Pinter Publishers, London, pp. 349â 369 Lundvall, B-A.,1993. Explaining inter-firm co-operation and innovation. In: Grabher, G. Ed.),The Embedded Firm Routledge, London, pp. 52â 64 Malecki, E. J.,Tootle, D. M.,1996. The role of networks in small firm competitiveness. International Journal of Technology Management 11, 43â 57 Mà nard, C.,1992. Why do agents cooperate? In: Proceedings of the Communication at CAESAR s Workshops. Paris Mowery, D c.,1983. The relationship between intrafirm and contractual forms of industrial research in American manufacturing, 1900â 1940. Explorations in Economic History 20, 351â 374 OCDE, 1992. Principes directeurs proposã s par lâ OCDE pour le recueil et lâ interprã tation des donnã es sur lâ innovation technologiqueâ Manuel dâ Oslo. OCDE, Paris OCDE, 1993. Les petites et moyennes Entreprises: Technologie et compã titivitã. OCDE, Paris Patel, P.,Pavitt, K.,1994. The continuing, widespread and neglected) importance of improvements in mechanical technologies. Research Policy 23, 533â 545 Pavitt, K.,1984. Sectoral patterns of technical change: towards a taxonomy and a theory. Research Policy 13, 343â 373 Pelikan, P.,1988. Can the imperfect innovation systems of capitalism be outperformed? In: Dosi, G. Ed.),Technical Change and Economic theory. Pinter Publishers, London pp. 370â 398 Perrin, J.-C.,1991. Analyse et à valuation des processus de production des techniques à partir des activitã s de conception In: de Bandt, J.,Foray, D. Eds. Lâ à valuation à conomique de la recherche et du changement Technique. Editions du CNRS Paris, pp. 276â 303 Richardson, G. B.,1972. The organisation of industry. The Economic Journal 82 (9), 883â 896 Rocha, F.,1999. Inter-firm technological co-operation: effects of absorptive capacity, firm-size and specialisation. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 8, 79â 103 Roper, S.,1998. Under-reporting of R&d in small firms: the impact on international R&d comparisons. Small Business Economics 12, 131â 135 Rosenfeld, S. A.,1996. Does co-operation enhance competitive -ness? Assessing the impacts of inter-firm collaboration Research Policy 25, 247â 263 Rothwell, R.,Zegveld, W.,1982. Innovation and the Small and Medium Sized Firm. Pinter Publishers, London Senker, J.,1995. Networks tacit knowledge in innovation Economies et Sociã tã s 29 (9), 99â 118 SESSI, 1996. Lâ innovation technologique dans lâ industrie. SESSI Paris SESSI, 1995. Lâ industrie Franã§aise. SESSI, Paris Teece, D. J.,1980. Economies of scope and the scope of the enterprise. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organisation 1 223â 247 Tether, B. S.,Smith, I. J.,Thwaites, A t.,1997. Smaller enterprises and innovation in the UK: the SPRU innovations database revisited. Research Policy 26 (3), 19â 32 Von Hippel, E.,1987. Co-operation between rivals: informal know-how trading. Research Policy 16, 291â 302 Williamson, O. E.,1989. Transaction cost economics. In Schmalensee, R.,Willig, R. Eds. Handbook of Industrial Organisation. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 135â 182 Williamson, O. E.,1991. Strategizing, economising, and economic organisation. Strategic Management Journal 12, 75â 94 Winter, S g.,1991. On coase, competence, and the corporation In: Williamson, O. E.,Winter, S g. Eds. The Nature of the Firm. Oxford university Press, New york, pp. 179â 195 Innovation, collaboration and SMES internal research capacities Introduction Industrial co-operation: from exchange to production Limits of the transaction cost theory Co-operation as a learning process SMES and external communication The crucial role of the manager during the innovation process The role of networks in SMES competitiveness Impact of cooperative relationships on successful innovation: analysis from a panel of French SMES Research methodology The sector of production of the innovation The technical partners The role of linkages to external resources Relationships between firms internal capabilities and successful innovations Relation between absorptive capacity and external learning Links between R&d intensity and successful innovation The contribution of executives to successful collaborative relationships The contribution of design office to successful collaborative relationships Conclusion Acknowledgements Appendix A References
Overtext Web Module V3.0 Alpha
Copyright Semantic-Knowledge, 1994-2011